But, there is a functional purpose of donating still usable but unwanted clothing, it increases the efficiency of resource use, despite looking worse on GDP figures. And Second Hand Clothes (SHC) are only charity for the organization that receives them in the rich world. That charity then bears the transactions cost of gathering and sorting through the clothes. They take the best clothes to donate, or in the case of thrift stores, sell. The rest is given to a for-profit exporter, who must bear the transactions cost of gathering, and sorting the clothes and finding buyers abroad. The clothes are bought by importers in poor countries and sold on local markets. This means the clothes are only sold in developing economies if they can compete on price with other options. Anyway, the author finds:
"used-clothing imports are found to have a negative impact on apparel and textile production in Africa, explaining roughly 40% of the decline in African apparel production and roughly 50% of the decline in apparel employment."
This is important because garment production has repeatedly been a step on the development ladder for poor countries, such as China and Bangladesh[1]. The logic being that hobbling domestic garment industries in poor countries can block their path to development. The author uses an instrumental regression technique to estimate the effect of SHC on domestic garment production and employment. When done correctly, the technique isolates the effects on the local garment industry to only SHC imports. For example, controlling for the effect of cheap imports from China.
However, this is not a per-se finding of net harm[2]. First, as the author plainly states, the paper looks only at the effect on the domestic garment industry, not the net effect on employment and income. Importers and sellers of SHC create local jobs that are not considered in the paper. The paper mentions that the garment industries are a very small proportion of GDP in the countries examined. This fact, and that the author found data on employment levels, leads me to believe he is looking at formal sector employment only. Most garment workers are in the informal sector, which the state fails to reliably measure. The result would be that the paper misses the majority of the garment industry. The paper also looks at the period 1980 – 2000, during which time local garment industries were declining and growth stagnating; a correlation that supports concerns of a blocked development path. The cut off just misses the recent impressive economic growth in many areas of Sub-Saharan Africa. This growth has occurred despite increasing SHC imports.
And then there is this statement in the paper that any economist knows to be true:
"In an open economy...the used-clothing imports will not affect domestic production, as domestic production is based on comparative advantage…and worldwide, rather than domestic, demand"
Ah! So it’s maybe harmful only if the receiving country has terrible economic policy. Sub-Saharan African countries have made a lot of progress in opening up their economies in the past couple decades, a process mostly missed by the paper’s time horizon. Either way, should we really not reduce waste in the rich world and benefit poor consumers because of that? And could a country possibly develop anyway with bad economic policy and more expensive clothing that benefits relatively better off producers?
That reminds me of the Import Substitution Industrialization (ISI) policies of Latin America in the latter half of the 20th century. Their intent was to replace foreign imports with domestic production to develop domestic manufacturing. This was accomplished through import tariffs and quotas that made foreign products more expensive and less available. The result was that domestic consumers paid more for lower quality. This benefited manufacturers with cozy relationships to policy makers at the expense of poorer domestic consumers. They were a failure and ended with a debt crisis. It’s true that Latin America experienced growth under the policies, higher than it experienced for almost two decades after ditching them. But it’s also true that a hangover is caused by drinking the night before[3].
At the same time, Latin America was being passed economically by East Asia, which developed through export led industrialization and relative openness to foreign goods. This, I think, is key. East Asia developed by producing cheap garments (and many other cheap labor intensive goods) by exporting them to the world market, rather than producing for domestic consumption. There is a lot of competition right now for cheap garment exports, and Africa generally has large logistic obstacles relative to East Asia. But their best strategy is to have more open economies and produce what they have a comparative advantage in. And let consumers benefit from increased purchasing power if imported goods are cheaper and better[4].
This is an intuitive result, it would be quite contrarian if it were the case that the world would be better off with rich consumers being more wasteful, and poor consumers facing higher prices.